Faustian Man's Demise Will Be Catabolic
Reading Aloud JMG's 'How Civilizations Fall: A Theory of Catabolic Collapse'
The End of Faustian Man: A Catabolic Collapse of Western Civilization- In the waning days of the Faustian spirit, the once unyielding drive for limitless progress, expansion, and domination is met with the brutal reality of catabolic collapse. This is not a sudden, cataclysmic end but a slow unravelling of Western civilization’s intricate systems. Once driven by ambition and an unrelenting pursuit of mastery over nature, Faustian Man faces the consequences of overconsumption, ecological exhaustion, and technological stagnation. The catabolic process begins with the depletion of the resources that powered the Industrial Revolution, followed by a gradual decay in political systems, economic structures, and social cohesion. The vitality that once fueled Europe’s empires, intellectual movements, and industrial growth fades into a low-energy, survival-based existence. The Faustian spirit, driven by boundless ambition, finally succumbs to the reality that no civilization --no matter how powerful--can transcend the natural limits of the world it inhabits.
For the past few decades & centuries, most of our understanding regarding How Past Civilizations have Risen & Fallen… has been severely tarnished by several peculiar trends.
On the one hand, we live in a Time of plenty unlike any in recorded Human History:
Modern man today has access to Energy, Metals, Minerals, & Materials that past Kings & Emperors could rarely get their hands on. The average Joe today can access more Aluminum than a King in premodern times could seize via warfare, trade, etc., over several years.
On the other hand, said plenty has not come to Modern man without considerable costs:
Today, Modern man is veritably both Energy Blind as well as Materials Blind.
He dreams & aspires to do things & play roles that are not just ludicrous but outright nonsensical & mathematically impossible. His imagination in the realm of fantasy has far outstripped the empirical, practical & pragmatic realities of his material condition.
Man, endowed by The Creator Most High with the faculties of Reason, is capable of many wonders. Yet, he is still a finite being whose Animal nature & Biophysical Limitations are crucial to understanding his condition. Modern man, however, seeks to up-end all of this:
Faustian Man seeks infinite expansion in not just the material plane but likewise that of the imagination. Limits are forever illusory for him, ready to be torn asunder by Sheer Willpower.
This has created an entire Civilization (i.e., Western Civilization & The Occident, writ large) that views itself as not just ‘Chosen’ to be above all the others but equally Privileged to somehow avoid their ignoble fates & calamities. For Faustian Man, the path is clear:
He will either March Out of the Caves & Into the Stars, Or He will Die on Earth in Nuclear Bonfires, which he himself alighted once he failed to accomplish his primary objective.
This Anthropocentric tendency has made Faustian Man exacerbate all of his sundry crises, whereby he thinks of himself as the focal point & the measure of all things.
When (for example) Faustian Man is told about the fundamental Limits of how much Energy & Metals exist for Mining, Usage, etc, on the Planet, he thinks that such a thing is a Farce, that there is instead an alternate set of explanations that can be utilized:
‘Technology & Human Innovation will fix it! We will find substitutes!’
‘Markets, Pricing & Human Determination will eventually solve this!’
‘Our Political Leaders Are Corrupt & Inept, that is why we have these issues!’
‘One Day, Someone Somewhere Somehow will find a way to push through!’
‘We can always Mine Mars & the Asteroid Belt! Space is the Answer!’
‘Robots & Fusion Power will soon make these Limits irrelevant!’
… etc, etc.
The end result of all these Romantic Fantasies has been perpetual Decline & Stagnation in Living Standards, Quality of Life, Infrastructure, etc., across the Western world, with little to no genuine understanding of what the True Predicament of this moment happens to be:
Faustian Man is presently projecting his own Romantic Fantasies onto Civilizations of the Past, fallaciously attributing to them things like (say) ‘Lack of Willpower,’ ‘Not enough Good Tech & Innovation,’ ‘Economic & Institutional bottlenecks,’ etc.:
He thinks their Decline & Fall were instances in which ‘Not enough of an effort’ was made. For Faustian Man, this way of doing Historiography, where Humans alone determine their fates & destinies, has been the norm in much of Academia for the past several decades.
The trouble, of course, is that such Anthropocentrism falls apart on even paltry scrutiny…
Enter .
Grandmaster of DOOM, Grand Archdruid, prolific author & polymath— In How Civilizations Fall: A Theory of Catabolic Collapse (2005), he notes that what undoes Human Civilization has a lot less to do with ‘Willpower’ & these other related notions…
& a whole lot more to do with Overshoot & Consumptive behaviour.
The Macro-Organism that is Human Civilization engages in Consumptive behaviour to expand & maintain itself, yet over Time, said behaviour means Overshoot such that sufficient resources no longer remain at a future point to continue adequate maintenance.
‘Collapse,’ the Grandmaster argues, is the Slow & Steady multi-centuries process by which the Macro-Organism simplifies down to fewer components & a more Resilient structure, which can once more be adequately maintained, given the new realities of Resource Shortfalls.
Ipso Facto, ‘Collapse’ is, on most days, a Marathon & not a Sprint.
While His Eminence John Michael Greer does not write on SubStack, one can find his writings elsewhere on Cyberspace:
Ecosophia.net (Official Blog)
( If you have not done so already, Please Subscribe to the Grandmaster on Ecosophia.net, Dear Readers & Listeners! His work is a must-read for DOOM-ers of all shapes & sizes & Young, aspiring DOOM Merchants like Yours Truly! 😘 )
Without further adieu, here is the entire essay in all its DOOM-ful splendour! 😉
How Civilizations Fall: A Theory of Catabolic Collapse
Originally Published in 2005, Now Hosted at Ecoshock.org: Full Essay
Catabolic Collapse: The Quiet Decline of Civilizations- Unlike traditional collapse models that depict sudden, catastrophic endings, catabolic collapse suggests that civilizations fall through a quiet, insidious process of decline. Over time, societies experience a gradual depletion of resources and a slow erosion of energy inputs, which weakens the foundational systems that once supported prosperity. Societies, once vibrant and dynamic, begin to shift into a lower-energy mode, where infrastructure decays, social bonds fray, and collective ambition wanes. This process can be seen in many ancient civilizations, from the Roman Empire to the Maya, which slowly lost the ability to maintain their complex systems. Catabolic collapse argues that these societies didn’t fall due to a singular external threat but through the long-term unsustainable consumption of resources, technological stagnation, and the gradual fragmentation of their internal systems. As modern societies face similar pressures--economic inequality, environmental crises, and overextension--this model provides a framework for understanding our own potential future.
Abstract
The collapse of complex human societies remains poorly understood and current theories fail to model important features of historical examples of collapse. Relationships among resources, capital, waste, and production form the basis for an ecological model of collapse in which production fails to meet maintenance requirements for existing capital. Societies facing such crises after having depleted essential resources risk catabolic collapse, a self-reinforcing cycle of contraction converting most capital to waste. This model allows key features of historical examples of collapse to be accounted for, and suggests parallels between successional processes in nonhuman ecosystems and collapse phenomena in human societies.
Keywords: collapse, ecology, resources, succession
Introduction
The Collapse of Complex Societies: A Mystery Yet to Be Fully Understood- The collapse of complex human societies--whether the fall of the Roman Empire, the demise of the Maya civilization, or the decline of the Industrial Age--remains one of history’s most elusive phenomena. Despite centuries of study, scholars are still struggling to fully understand why these once-thriving civilizations ultimately disintegrated. Current collapse theories often focus on simplistic factors--economic failures, invasions, or environmental disasters--but these explanations miss critical elements such as social cohesion, technological stagnation, and ecological feedback loops. The true causes of societal collapse are far more complex and multifaceted, requiring an interdisciplinary approach that combines sociology, anthropology, environmental science, and systems theory. In today’s world, where global societies face mounting challenges, understanding the dynamics of collapse could offer valuable lessons for preventing or mitigating the decline of modern civilizations.
The collapse of complex human societies, while a subject of perennial scholarly and popular fascination, remains poorly understood. Tainter (1988), surveying previous attempts to account for the demise of civilizations, noted that most proposed explanations of collapse failed to adequately describe causative mechanisms, and relied either on ad-hoc hypotheses based on details of specific cases or, by contrast, essentially mystical claims (e.g., that civilizations have lifespans like those of individual biological organisms). In another recent survey of collapses in history (Yoffee and Cowgill 1988), contributors proposed widely divergent explanatory models to account for broadly similar processes of decline and breakdown.
Tainter (1988) proposed a general theory of collapse, in which complex societies break down when increasing complexity results in negative marginal returns, so that a decrease in sociopolitical complexity yields net benefits to people in the society. This theory has important strengths, and models many features of the breakdown of civilizations, but it fails to account for other factors, especially the temporal dimensions of the process. Tainter defines collapse as a process of marked sociopolitical simplification unfolding on a timescale of “no more than a few decades” (Tainter, 1988, p. 4), replacing an unsustainably high level of complexity with a lower, more sustainable level. Many of the examples he cites, however, fail to fit this description, but occurred over a period of centuries rather than decades (see Table 1) and involved an extended process of progressive disintegration rather than a rapid shift from an unsustainable state to a sustainable one.
The best documented examples of collapse, such as the fall of the western Roman empire, show a distinctive temporal pattern even more difficult to square with Tainter’s theory. Thus, during the collapse of Roman power, each of a series of crises led to loss of social complexity and the establishment of temporary stability at a less complex level. Each such level then proved to be unsustainable in turn, and was followed by a further crisis and loss of complexity (Gibbon 1776-88; Tainter, 1988; Grant, 1990). In many regions, furthermore, the sociopolitical complexity remaining after the empire’s final disintegration was far below the level that had existed in the same area prior to its inclusion in the Imperial system. Thus Britain in the late pre-Roman Iron Age, for example, had achieved a stable and flourishing agricultural society with nascent urban centers and international trade connections, while the same area remained depopulated, impoverished, and politically chaotic for centuries following the collapse of imperial authority (Snyder 2003).
An alternative model based on perspectives from human ecology offers a more effective way to understand the collapse process. This conceptual model, the theory of catabolic collapse, explains the breakdown of complex societies as the result of a self-reinforcing cycle of decline driven by interactions among resources, capital, production, and waste. Previous work on the human ecology of past civilizations (e.g., Hughes, 1975; Sanders et al., 1979; Ponting, 1992; Elvin, 1993; Webster, 2002) and attempts to project the impact of ecological factors on present societies (e.g., Catton, 1980; Gever et al., 1986; Meadows et al., 1992; Duncan, 1993; Heinberg, 2002) have yielded data and analytical tools from which a general theory of the collapse of complex societies may be developed. This will be attempted here.
The Human Ecology Of Collapse
The Human Ecology of Collapse: A Systems Approach to Societal Decline- In the context of the human ecology of collapse, societies are seen as complex systems that interact dynamically with their environment. Over time, civilizations develop systems of agriculture, infrastructure, and trade that depend heavily on natural resources. As these systems become more advanced, they also become more vulnerable to ecological changes. The collapse of a society occurs when environmental factors--whether climate shifts, resource depletion, or ecosystem collapse--interact with internal societal pressures such as political instability or economic failure. The key to understanding collapse lies in systemic thinking, recognizing that the collapse of civilizations is rarely caused by one single factor, but by a complex web of ecological, social, and economic interactions. This approach can inform contemporary strategies for avoiding collapse, as modern societies face environmental degradation, overpopulation, and climate change, which threaten to disrupt the delicate balance of human ecological systems.
At the highest level of abstraction, any human society includes four core elements. Resources (R) are naturally occurring factors in the environment which can be exploited by a particular society, but have not yet been extracted and incorporated into the society’s flows of energy and material. Resources include material resources such as iron ore not yet mined and naturally occurring soil fertility that has not yet been exhausted by the society’s agricultural methods, human resources such as people not yet included in the workforce, and information resources such as scientific discoveries which can be made by the society's methods of research but have not yet been made. While the resources available to any society, even the simplest, are numerous, complex, and changing, this conceptual model treats resources as a single variable. This radical oversimplification is acceptable solely because it allow certain large-scale patterns to be seen clearly, and permits one model to be applied to the widest possible range of societies.
Capital (C) consists of all factors from whatever source that have been incorporated into the society’s flows of energy and material but are capable of further use. Capital includes physical capital such as food, fields, tools, and buildings; human capital such as laborers and scientists; social capital such as social hierarchies and economic systems; and information capital such as technical knowledge. While a market system is a form of social capital, and currency and coinage are forms of physical capital, it should be noted that money as such is a mechanism for allocating and controlling capital rather than a form of capital in its own right. While the capital stocks of every society are diverse, complex, and changing, again, for the sake of exposition, this model treats all capital as a single variable.
Waste (W) consists of all factors that have been incorporated into the society’s flows of energy and material, and exploited to the point that they are incapable of further use. Materials used or converted into pollutants, tools and laborers at the end of their useful lives, and information garbled or lost, all become waste. All waste is treated as a single variable for the purpose of this conceptual model.
Production (P) is the process by which existing capital and resources are combined to create new capital and waste. The quality and quantity of new capital created by production are functions of the resources and existing capital used in production. Resources and existing capital may be substituted for one another in production, but the relation between the two is nonlinear and complete substitution is impossible. As the use of resources approaches zero, in particular, maintaining any given level of production requires exponential increases in the use of existing capital, due to the effect of decreasing marginal return (Clark and Haswell, 1966; Wilkinson, 1973; Tainter, 1988). For the purpose of this model, all production is treated as a single variable.
In any human society, resources and capital enter the production process, and new capital and waste leave it. Capital is also subject to waste outside production – uneaten food suffers spoilage, for example, and unemployed laborers still grow old and die. Thus maintenance of a steady state requires new capital from production to equal waste from production and capital:
where C(p) is new capital produced, W(p) is existing capital converted to waste in the production of new capital, and W(c) is existing capital converted to waste outside of production. The sum of W(p) and W(c) is M(p), maintenance production, the level of production necessary to maintain capital stocks at existing levels. Thus Equation 1 can be more simply put:
Societies which move from a steady state into a state of expansion produce more than necessary to maintain existing capital stocks:
In the absence of effective limits to growth, once started, this expansion becomes a self-reinforcing process, because additional capital can be brought into the production process, where it generates yet more new capital, which can be brought into the production process in turn. The westward expansion of the United States in the 19th century offers a well-documented example; in a resource-rich environment, increases in human capital through immigration and increases in information capital through development of new agricultural technologies increased production, driving increases in physical capital through geographical expansion, settling of arable land, manufacturing, etc., which increased production again and drove further increases across the spectrum of capital (Billington 1982). This process may be called an anabolic cycle.
The self-reinforcing aspect of an anabolic cycle is limited by two factors that tend to limit increases in C(p). First, resources may not be sufficient to maintain indefinite expansion. Here the use of “resources” as a single variable must be set aside briefly. Each resource has a replenishment rate, r(R), the rate at which new stocks of the resource become available to the society. For any given resource and society at any given time, r(R) is a weighted product of the rates of natural production, new discovery of existing deposits, and development of alternative resources capable of filling the same role in production. Over time, since discovery and the development of replacements are both subject to decreasing marginal returns (Clark and Haswell, 1966; Wilkinson, 1973; Tainter, 1988), r(R) approaches asymptotically the combined rate at which the original resource and replacements are created by natural processes.
Each resource also has a rate of use by the society, d(R), and the relationship between d(R) and r(R) forms a core element in the model. Resources used faster than their replenishment rate, d(R)/r(R) >1, become depleted; a depleted resource must be replaced by existing capital to maintain production, and the demand for capital increases exponentially as depletion continues. Thus, unless all of a society’s necessary resources have an unlimited replenishment rate, C(p) cannot increase indefinitely because d(R) will eventually exceed r(R), leading to depletion and exponential increases in capital required to maintain C(p) at any given level. Liebig’s law of the minimum suggests that for any given society, the essential resource with the highest value for d(R)/r(R) may be used as a working value of d(R)/r(R) for resources as a whole.
Resource depletion is thus one of the two factors that tends to overcome the momentum of an anabolic cycle. The second is inherent in the relationship between capital and waste. As capital stocks increase, M(p) rises, since W(c) rises proportionally to total capital; more capital requires more maintenance and replacement. M(p) also rises as C(p) rises, since increased production requires increased use of capital and thus increased W(p), or conversion of capital to waste in the production process. All other factors being equal, the effect of W(c) is to make M(p) rise faster than C(p), since not all capital is involved in production at any given time, but all capital is constantly subject to conversion to waste. Increased C(p) relative to M(p) can be generated by decreasing capital stocks to decrease W(c); by slowing the conversion of capital to waste to decrease W(c) and/or W(p); by increasing the fraction of capital involved in production, to increase C(p); or by increasing the intake of resources for production, thus increasing C(p). If these are not done, or prove insufficient to meet the needs of the situation, M(p) will rise to equal or exceed C(p) and bring the anabolic cycle to a halt.
Broadly speaking, a society facing the end of an anabolic cycle faces a choice between two strategies. One strategy is to move toward a steady state in which C(p) = M(p), and d(R) = r(R) for every economically significant resource. Barring the presence of environmental limits, this requires social controls to keep capital stocks down to a level at which maintenance costs can be met from current production, and maintain intake of resources at or below replenishment rates. This can require difficult collective choices, but as long as resource availability remains stable, controls on capital growth stay in place, and the society escapes major exogenous crises, this strategy can be pursued indefinitely.
The alternative is to attempt to prolong the anabolic cycle through efforts to accelerate intake of resources through military conquest, new technology, or other means. Since increasing production increases W(p) and increasing capital stocks lead to increased W(c), however, such efforts drive further increases in M(p). A society that attempts to maintain an anabolic cycle indefinitely must therefore expand its use of resources at an ever-increasing rate to keep C(p) from dropping below M(p). Since this exacerbates problems with depletion, as discussed above, this strategy may prove counterproductive.
If the attempt to achieve a steady state fails, or if efforts at increasing resource intake fall irrevocably behind rising M(p), a society enters a state of contraction, in which production of new capital does not make up for losses due to waste:
The process of contraction takes two general forms, depending on the replenishment rate of resources used by the society. A society that uses resources at or below replenishment rate (d(R)/r(R) = 1), when production of new capital falls short of maintenance needs, enters a maintenance crisis in which capital of all kinds cannot be maintained and is converted to waste: physical capital is destroyed or spoiled, human populations decline in number, large-scale social organizations disintegrate into smaller and more economical forms, and information is lost. Because resources are not depleted, maintenance crises are generally self-limiting. As capital is lost, M(p) declines steeply, while declines in C(p) due to capital loss are cushioned to some extent by the steady supply of resources. This allows a return to a steady state or the start of a new anabolic cycle once the conversion of capital to waste brings M(p) back below C(p).
A society that uses resources beyond replenishment rate (d(R)/r(R) > 1), when production of new capital falls short of maintenance needs, risks a depletion crisis in which key features of a maintenance crisis are amplified by the impact of depletion on production. As M(p) exceeds C(p) and capital can no longer be maintained, it is converted to waste and unavailable for use. Since depletion requires progressively greater investments of capital in production, the loss of capital affects production more seriously than in an equivalent maintenance crisis. Meanwhile further production, even at a diminished rate, requires further use of depleted resources, exacerbating the impact of depletion and the need for increased capital to maintain production. With demand for capital rising as the supply of capital falls, C(p) tends to decrease faster than M(p) and perpetuate the crisis. The result is a catabolic cycle, a self-reinforcing process in which C(p) stays below M(p) while both decline. Catabolic cycles may occur in maintenance crises if the gap between C(p) and M(p) is large enough, but tend to be self-limiting in such cases. In depletion crises, by contrast, catabolic cycles can proceed to catabolic collapse, in which C(p) approaches zero and most of a society’s capital is converted to waste.
A society in a depletion crisis does not inevitably proceed to catabolic collapse. If depletion is limited, so that decreased demand for resources as a consequence of diminished production brings d(R) back below r(R), the accelerated fall in C(p) may not take place and the crisis may play out much like a maintenance crisis. If the gap between C(p) and M(p) is modest, nonproductive capital may be diverted to production to raise C(p) or preferentially converted to waste to bring down M(p), forcing C(p) and M(p) temporarily into balance in order to buy time for a transition to a steady state. A society in which depletion is advanced and M(p) rapidly increasing relative to C(p), though, may not be able to escape catabolic collapse even if such steps are taken. Cultural and political factors may also make efforts to avoid catabolic collapse difficult to accomplish, or indeed to contemplate.
Testing The Model
The Spectrum of Collapse: From Maintenance Crisis to Catabolic Breakdown- Collapse is rarely a straightforward path, and the distinction between a maintenance crisis and a depletion crisis reflects only the two extremes of a complex continuum. A maintenance crisis emerges when societal institutions--from political systems to economic models--fail to adapt to changing needs or external pressures. These crises often involve institutional decay and social fragmentation, but recovery is possible through adaptation, reform, or rediscovery of collective action. Conversely, a depletion crisis occurs when a society’s ecological capital--its natural resources, energy, and basic subsistence systems--are exhausted to the point where the society can no longer support itself. In these cases, catabolic collapse occurs slowly, as complex systems unravel piece by piece, often leaving a fractured, lower-energy society behind. In most cases, the collapse process involves elements of both crises, as political stagnation accelerates the depletion of resources, and environmental degradation exacerbates institutional breakdown. The real question for modern societies is not whether one type of collapse will occur, but how they can navigate these crises to avoid falling entirely into either extreme.
These two forms of collapse, maintenance crisis leading to recovery and depletion crisis leading to catabolic collapse, are to some extent ideal types, and form two ends of a complex spectrum of societal breakdown. Most historical examples of collapse fall somewhere in the range between. The limitations of the abstract and extremely simplified model on which the theory is based should also be kept firmly in mind when attempting to apply it to past or present examples. Still, a survey of historical examples shows that many of these have features which support the model proposed in this paper.
Closest to the maintenance-crisis end of the spectrum are tribal societies such as the Kachin of Burma. Kachin communities cycle up and down from relatively decentralized (gumlao) to relatively centralized (shan) social forms without significant losses of physical, human, or information capital. In this case anabolic cycles lead to the growth of organizational capital in the form of relatively centralized social forms, but the maintenance costs of this organizational capital prove to be unsustainable, leading to maintenance crises, loss of social capital, and the restoration of less resource- and capital-intensive social forms (Leach, 1954).
Essentially the same process on a larger and more destructive scale characterizes the history of imperial China from the tenth century BCE to the end of the nineteenth century CE.. Efficient cereal agriculture and local market economies provided the foundation for a series of anabolic cycles resulting in the establishment of centralized imperial dynastic states (Gates, 1996; Di Cosmo, 1999). These anabolic cycles drove increases in population, public works such as canals and flood control projects, and sociopolitical organization, which proved unsustainable over the long term. As maintenance costs exceeded the imperial government’s resources, repeated maintenance crises led to the breakup of national unity, invasion by neighboring peoples, loss of infrastructure and steep declines in population (Ho, 1970; Di Cosmo, 1999). Imperial China’s resource base had a relatively high replenishment rate, due largely to the long-term sustainability of traditional Chinese agriculture and the use of human and animal muscle as the primary energy sources, and any significant depletion was made good once population levels dropped (Elvin, 1993). Though resource depletion played a limited role, the maintenance crises of imperial China were self-limiting and resulted in contraction to more modest levels of population and sociopolitical organization, rather than the total collapse of the society.
The collapse of the western Roman Empire, by contrast, was a catabolic collapse driven by a combined maintenance and resource crisis. While the ancient Mediterranean world, like imperial China, was primarily dependent on readily replenished resources, the Empire itself was the product of an anabolic cycle fueled by easily depleted resources and driven by Roman military superiority. Beginning in the third century BCE, Roman expansion transformed the capital of other societies into resources for Rome as country after country was conquered and stripped of movable wealth. Each new conquest increased the Roman resource base and helped pay for further conquests. After the first century CE, though, further expansion failed to pay its own costs. All remaining peoples within the reach of Rome were either barbarian tribes with little wealth, such as the Germans, or rival empires capable of defending themselves, such as the Parthians (Jones 1974). Without income from new conquests, the maintenance costs of empire proved unsustainable, and a catabolic cycle followed rapidly. The first major breakdown in the imperial system came in 166 CE, and further crises followed until the Western empire ceased to exist in 476 CE (Grant 1990, Grant 1999).
The Roman collapse has an instructive feature which offers further support to the model presented here. In 297 the emperor Diocletian divided the empire into western and eastern halves. Coordination between them waned, and by the death of Theodosius I in 395, the two halves of the empire were effectively independent states. Since the western empire produced 1/3 the revenues of the eastern empire, but had more than twice as much northern frontier to defend against barbarian encroachments, this placed most of the original empire’s vulnerabilities in one half and most of its remaining resources in the other. In terms of the catabolic collapse model, the eastern Empire allowed massive quantities of relatively unproductive, high-maintenance capital to be converted to waste, bringing its M(p) below its remaining C(p) and breaking out of the catabolic cycle. The eastern empire’s territory decreased further with the Muslim conquests of the seventh and eighth centuries CE; while this was involuntary the effects were the same. Successfully shifting to a level of organization that could be supported sustainably by trade and agriculture within a more manageable territory, the eastern Empire survived for nearly a millennium longer than its western twin (Bury 1923).
Near the depletion crisis end of the spectrum is the collapse of the Lowland Classic Maya in the eighth, ninth, and tenth centuries of the Common Era. The most widely accepted model of the Maya collapse holds on demographic and paleoecological evidence that Maya populations grew to a level that could not be indefinitely supported by Mayan agricultural practices on the nutrient-poor laterite soils of the Yucatan lowlands. In terms of the present model, the key resource of soil fertility was used at a rate exceeding its replenishment rate, and suffered severe depletion as a result. Mayan polities also invested a large proportion of C(p) in monumental building programs, which raised maintenance costs but could not be readily used for production, and maintained these programs up to the beginning of the Terminal Classic period. The result was a “rolling collapse” over two centuries, from c. 750 CE to c. 950 CE, in which Lowland Maya populations declined precipitously and scores of urban centers were abandoned to the jungle (Willey and Shimkin 1973, Lowe 1985, Webster 2002).
The Lowland Classic Maya collapse is particularly suggestive in that it appears to have been preceded by at least two previous breakdowns. Preclassic sites such as El Mirador and Becan show many of the same artistic and cultural elements as Classic Maya urban centers, but were abandoned in a poorly documented earlier collapse around 150 CE (Webster 2002). A second episode, the so-called Hiatus between the Early Classic and Late Classic periods (500-600 CE), saw sharp declines in monumental building and evidence for political decentralization (Willey 1974). Whether these events were maintenance crises preceding the final resource crisis of the Terminal Classic, or whether some other explanation is called for, is difficult to determine from the available evidence.
Features of comparative sociology outside the realm of collapse processes also offer support to the catabolic collapse model. One implication of the model is that societies which persist over extended periods will tend to have social mechanisms for limiting the growth of capital, and thus artificially lowering M(p) below C(p). Such mechanisms do in fact exist in a wide range of societies. Among the most common are systems in which modest amounts of unproductive capital are regularly converted to waste. Examples include aspects of the potlatch economy among Native Americans of northwest North America (Kotschar, 1950; Rosman, 1971; Beck, 1993) and the ritual deposition of prestige metalwork in lakes and rivers by Bronze and Iron Age peoples in much of western Europe (Bradley, 1990; Randsborg, 1995). Such systems have been interpreted in many ways (Michaelson, 1979), but in terms of the model presented here, one of their functions is to divert some of C(p) away from capital stocks requiring maintenance, thus artificially lowering W(c) and make a catabolic cycle less likely.
Such practices clearly have many other meanings and functions within societies. Nor does this interpretation require any awareness within societies that systems of capital destruction prevent catabolic cycles. Rather, if such systems make catabolic collapse less likely, cultures that adopt such systems for other reasons would be more likely to survive over the long term and to pass on such cultural elements to neighboring or successor societies.
Conclusion: Collapse as a Succession Process
Collapse as a Succession Process: Gradual Breakdown and Adaptation- Collapse is not an abrupt event but a succession process that unfolds over time, marked by successive stages of societal decline, adaptation, and transformation. Initially, a society may experience a maintenance crisis, where its institutions and systems begin to stagnate or falter under the weight of internal pressures. This can lead to social fragmentation and the breakdown of key structures like governance, trade, and infrastructure. However, these early stages often leave room for adaptation--reforms, reorganization, or decentralization--that can delay the final collapse. Over time, however, if these adaptive efforts fail to address underlying resource limitations or ecological degradation, a depletion crisis ensues, where a society’s ecological capital is exhausted. This leads to a catabolic collapse, a slow and irreversible disintegration where social and economic systems degrade progressively. Collapse as a succession process thus involves a gradual, multifaceted breakdown, where each stage builds on and reinforces the next, ultimately reshaping the nature of the society that once existed.
Even within the social sciences, the process by which complex societies give way to smaller and simpler ones has often been presented in language drawn from literary tragedy, as though the loss of sociocultural complexity necessarily warranted a negative value judgment. This is understandable, since the collapse of civilizations often involves catastrophic human mortality and the loss of priceless cultural treasures, but like any value judgment it can obscure important features of the matter at hand.
A less problematic approach to the phenomenon of collapse derives from the idea of succession, a basic concept in the ecology of nonhuman organisms. Succession describes the process by which an area not yet occupied by living things is colonized by a variety of biotic assemblages, called seres, each replacing a prior sere and then being replaced by a later, until the process concludes with a stable, self-perpetuating climax community (Odum 1969).
One feature of succession in many different environments is a difference in resource use between earlier and later seres. Species characteristic of earlier seral stages tend to maximize control of resources and production of biomass per unit time, even at the cost of inefficiency; thus such species tend to maximize production and distribution of offspring even when this means the great majority of offspring fail to reach reproductive maturity. Species typical of later seres, by contrast, tend to maximize the efficiency of their resource use, even at the cost of limits to biomass production and the distribution of individual organisms; thus these species tend to maximize energy investment in individual offspring even when this means that offspring are few and the species fails to occupy all available niche spaces. Species of the first type, or R-selected species, have specialized to flourish opportunistically in disturbed environments, while those of the second type, or K-selected species, have specialized to form stable biotic communities that change only with shifts in the broader environment (Odum 1969).
Human societies and nonhuman species cannot be equated in a simplistic manner, but the radical differences in subsistence and production strategies among human societies allow them to be compared to distinct biotic groups in certain contexts. Human societies enter into common ecological relationships such as symbiosis, commensality, parasitism, predation, and competitive exclusion with other societies. Thus processes by which human societies are replaced by others may be usefully compared to succession to see if common features emerge.
The model of catabolic collapse suggests one such common feature. As outlined above, societies differ in their response to changes in resource availability and maintenance costs. The spectrum of response ranges from adjustment to a steady state, through a history of repeated maintenance crises and partial breakdowns followed by recoveries, to severe depletion crisis and total collapse. These differences, according to the model presented here, unfold from differing relationships among resources, capital, production, and waste, especially the relationships between capital production and maintenance, C(p)/M(p), and between use and replenishment rates of resources, d(R)/r(R).
These parallel differences between R-selected and K-selected nonhuman species. A society that maximizes its production of capital, like an R-selected species, prospers in an environment with substantial uncaptured resources but falters once these are exhausted. Its successors are likely to be societies that, like K- selected species, use key resources more sustainably at the cost of decreased production of capital. Nonhuman climax communities also typically display a higher diversity of species, but a lower population per species, than earlier seral stages, and produce notably lower volumes of biomass per unit time (Odum 1969).
Broadly similar changes often distinguish precollapse and postcollapse societies. Thus the collapse of the western Roman Empire, for example, could be seen as a succession process in which one seral stage, dominated by a single sociopolitical “species” that maximized capital production at the cost of inefficiency, was replaced by a more diverse community of societies, consisting of many less populous “species” better adapted to their own local conditions, and producing capital at lower but more sustainable rates. Analyses that portray this transformation as pure tragedy miss important aspects, since the Roman collapse enabled other societies to emerge from Rome’s shadow, and launched major cultural initiatives such as vernacular literatures in the ancestors of today’s Celtic, Germanic, and Romance languages (Wiseman 1997). As with any succession process, there were gainers as well as losers. If a lapse into fantasy may be excused, were nonhuman biota literate and interested in their past, a history of lake eutrophication written by meadow grasses would differ sharply from one written by fish.
Since humans have capacities for change that most species lack, the same human individuals can change from fish to grass, so to speak, composing an “R- selected” production-maximizing society at one time and its “K-selected” sustainability-maximizing replacement at a later time. The example of the Kachin cited above shows that this is not merely a theoretical possibility. However, as other cited examples and the general evidence of history suggest, such a change is not inevitable. The possibility of maintenance crisis needs to be considered whenever a society shows signs of being unable to maintain its existing capital, and the possibility of depletion crisis followed by catabolic collapse cannot be excluded whenever capital production depends on the use of resources at rates significantly above their rate of replacement.
Such assessments of past and present societies, in order to achieve a high degree of analytic or predictive value, require careful quantitative analysis of a sort this paper has not attempted. Since each element in the conceptual model presented here stands for a diverse and constantly changing set of variables, such analysis offers significant challenges, and in many historical examples it may be impossible to go beyond proxy measurements of uncertain value for crucial variables. However, general patterns corresponding to the catabolic collapse model may be easier to extract from incomplete data. Any society that displays broad increases in most measures of capital production coupled with signs of serious depletion of key resources, in particular, may be considered a potential candidate for catabolic collapse.
Collapse and Societal Decline: The Role of Human Ecology and Malthusian Theory- Throughout history, societies have risen and fallen, but the underlying causes of collapse and societal decline remain a subject of debate. Human ecology, the relationship between human societies and their environment, offers a crucial framework for understanding these processes. Malthusian theory, which posits that population growth will inevitably outstrip resource availability, provides a foundational lens for analyzing societal collapse. Societies often face breakdowns when they exceed their ecological limits--whether through resource depletion, environmental degradation, or unsustainable economic models. As human populations grow and consumption increases, the stresses on ecosystems become unsustainable, leading to the slow decay of complex social systems. Exploring catabolic collapse--a slow, systemic degradation of infrastructure, economy, and culture--can offer insights into how these processes unfold in modern contexts, where ecological limits are increasingly tested by industrialization, urbanization, and climate change.
Your Support is vital for Smelting the DOOM & keeping it HOT & FRESH off the Furnace!
If you enjoyed the read, I would greatly appreciate it if you subscribed to a Monthly or Yearly pledge to support my work so that I may continue Smelting DOOM for your displeasure!
Alternatively, you can tip here:
Thank You, Dear Readers, for all your Support!
References
Beck, M.G. (1993). Potlatch: native ceremony and myth on the Northwest Coast. Anchorage: Alaska Northwest.
Billington, R.A. (1982). Westward expansion: a history of the American frontier. New York: Macmillan.
Bradley, R. (1990). The passage of arms: an archaeological analysis of prehistoric hoards and votive deposits. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bury, J.B. (1923). History of the later Roman empire. London: Macmillan.
Catton, W.R., Jr. (1980). Overshoot: the ecological basis of revolutionary change. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
Clark, C., and Haswell, M. (1966). The economics of subsistence agriculture. London: Macmillan.
Corning, P.A. (1983). The synergism hypothesis. New York: McGraw-Hill.
----- (2002). ‘Devolution’ as an opportunity to test the ‘synergism hypothesis’ and a cybernetic theory of political systems. Systems Research and Behavioral Science 19:1 pp. 3-24.
Di Cosmo, N. (1999) State formation and periodization in inner Asia. International History Review 20:2, pp. 287-309.
Duncan, R.C. (1993).The life-expectancy of industrial civilization: the decline to global equilibrium.Population and Environment, 14(4), pp. 325-357.
Elvin, M. (1993). Three thousand years of unsustainable growth: China’s environment from archaic times to the present. East Asian History 6, pp. 7-46.
Gates, H. (1996). China’s motor: a thousand years of petty capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Gever, J., Kaufman, R., Skole, D., and Vorosmarty, C. (1986). Beyond oil: the threat to food and fuel in the coming decades. Cambridge: Ballinger.
Gibbon, E. (1776-88). The decline and fall of the Roman empire. New York: Modern Library.
Grant, M. (1990). The fall of the Roman empire. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.
----- (1999). The collapse and recovery of the Roman empire. London: Routledge.
Hughes, J. Donald (1975). Ecology in ancient civilizations. Albuquerque: University of New MexicoPress.
Jones, A.H.M. (1974). The Roman economy: studies in ancient economic and administrative history. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Heinberg, R. (2002). The party’s over: oil, war, and the fate of industrial societies. Vancouver: New Society.
Ho, P.-T. (1970). Economic and institutional factors in the decline of the Chinese empire. The economic decline of empires, ed C.M. Cipolla (pp. 264-77). London: Methuen.
Kotschar, V.F. (1950). Fighting with property: a study of Kwakiutl potlatching and warfare, 1792-1930. Seattle: University of Washington Press.
Leach, E.R. (1954). Political systems of highland Burma. Boston: Beacon Press.
Lowe, J.W.G. (1985). The dynamics of apocalypse: a systems simulation of the classic Maya collapse. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.
McNeill, W.H. (1998). Plagues and peoples. New York: Anchor.
Meadows, D.H., Meadows, D.L., and Randers, J., Beyond the limits. Post Mills, VT: Chelsea Green, (1992).
Michaelson, D.R. (1979). From ethnography to ethnology: a study of the conflict of interpretations of the southern Kwakiutl potlatch. Ph.D diss., New School for Social Research.
Odum, E. (1969). The strategy of ecosystem development. Science 164, pp. 262-70.
Ponting, C. (1992). A green history of the world: the environment and the collapse of great civilizations. New York: St. Martin’s.
Randsborg, K. (1995). Hjortspring: warfare and sacrifice in early Europe. Aarhus: Aarhus University Press.
Rosman, A., and Rubel, P.G. (1971). Feasting with mine enemy: rank and exchange among Northwest Coast societies. New York: Columbia University Press.
Sanders, W.T., Parsons, J.A., and Santley, R.S. (1979). The basin of Mexico: ecological processes in the evolution of a civilization. New York: Academic Press.
Snyder, C.A. (2003). The Britons. Oxford: Blackwell.
Tainter, J.A. (1988). The collapse of complex societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Webster, D.L. (2002). The fall of the ancient Maya: solving the mystery of the Maya collapse. London: Thames and Hudson.
Wilkinson, R.G. (1973). Poverty and progress: an ecological model of economic development. London: Methuen.
Willey, G.R. (1974). The classic Maya hiatus: a ‘rehearsal’ for the collapse? Mesoamerican Archeology: New Approaches, ed. N. Hammond (pp. 417-30). London: Duckworth.
Willey, G.R., and Shimkin, D.B. (1973). The Maya collapse: a summary view. The classic Maya collapse, ed. T.P. Culbert (pp. 457-501). Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.
Wiseman, J. (1997). The post-Roman world. Archaeology 50:6, p. 12-17.
Yoffee, N., and Cowgill, G., eds. (1988). The collapse of ancient states and civilizations. Tucson: University of New Mexico Press.
Consider:
1. We develop fusion energy technology.
2. AI
3. Nanotechnology